Friday, January 30, 2015

Dinner with Haavelmo

The student magazine at TSE (TSEconomist) asked some of us to tell them with which thinker of the past we would like to have dinner. Here is my answer.


If I was to have dinner with an economist of the past, it would probably be Trygve Haavelmo. His 1944 Econometrica paper “TheProbability Approach in Econometrics” is for me a milestone for econometrics and applied economics, and, let’s be bold, economics in general. I read it several times and continue reading it regularly. Each time, I discover a novel gem. This paper laid out the ground for applied work in economics with a sound statistical basis but also taking into account the specificities of our field, as for example the existence of interdependence and equilibrium relationships. This paper inspired the subsequent work of the Cowles Commission that forms the basis of the econometrics curriculum that we teach. 

But this paper is also so much more than theoretical econometrics. It is a paper about epistemology, how and why we can do research in economics. I think the views Haavelmo expressed in this paper are so deep that they implicitly structured how applied research in economics has been conducted until the late 80s. And in some of his views, you also see the nascent credibility revolution coming: Haavelmo coined the term natural experiments (actually, Josh Angrist, the modern proponent of this approach, directly attributes the term to him) and he also insisted heavily on setting up a design of experiments with each economic theory, because, in his own words: “Our guard against futile speculations is the requirement that the results of our theoretical considerations are, ultimately, to be compared with some real phenomena.” He also said that “What makes a piece of mathematical economics not only mathematics but also economics is, I believe, this: When we set up a system of theoretical relationships and use economic names for the otherwise purely theoretical variables involved, we have in mind some actual experiment, or some design of an experiment, which we could at least imagine arranging, in order to measure those quantities in real economic life that we think might obey the laws imposed on their theoretical namesakes”. 

What I would love to talk to him about is why he did not promote much more the experimental method in economics. My understanding of his paper is that, at some point, he abandons all hope of ever conducting experiments in economics and settles for something else, namely modelling what we do not know, the confounding factors. He uses an analogy with physics, saying that we have to model the forces of friction because we cannot run experiments in a vacuum. I think this approach was wrongheaded and contributed to mixing science with engineering for a long time in economics. I would also ask him why, despite the repeated failures of the approach that he proposed, and that he acknowledged repeatedly, in his 1958 speech  as a president of the EconometricSociety, and in his 1989 Nobel prize speech, he blamed the theory instead of blaming the method and putting experiments back into the picture. I would also love to discuss with him the exciting direction that economics is taking now, with more use of experiments for testing theories and policies, and the novel and welcome approach of testing the predictions of structural models againstpolicy changes.

Finally, because Trygve did not seem like a funny guy, I might also invite David Hume to take part. Apart from being my favorite philosopher, he was nice and charming fellow and would for sure cheer us up. Oh, and he also basically invented the notion of counterfactual that is crucial for causal analysis. That would be some dinner!

Monday, January 26, 2015

Land reallocation and the structural transformation of the French agriculture

I have recently started to work on an exciting new project about land reallocation and the structural transformation of French agriculture. In this post, I'll present the motivation for the project and how I plan to conduct  it.

Motivation

Understanding why countries are poor or rich, and how to unleash their growth opportunities is a key question in economics, for obvious reasons. One theory explaining why some countries are poor is factor misallocation. For some reason, factors as land or capital may end up being distributed unefficiently - maybe divided in too small farms or too scattered pieces, or not allocating enough land or capital to the more able managers. According to this theory, reallocating factors in a more efficient manner would unleash strong growth. There is growing evidence that  some kind of factor misallocation is at play, but we lack direct evidence that a policy of active reallocation of factors of production can indeed increase productivity. This is key because providing evidence of factor misallocation does not mean that a policy of reallocation would increase productivity. Moreover, studying an actual event of land reallocation might help in undertsanding how factor misallocation impairs productivity growth. Is that because of poor organization of factors of production, as for examples farms divided in scattered pieces, or because very productive farmers were not allocated enough land, or because it unleashed the realization of more productive investments? Finally, such an approach might also shed light on the sources of misallocation: why the market forces were not enough to allocate the factors of production efficiently?

To shed light on this issue, my project is to use a major land reallocation experiment that took place in France, called "reparcelling" (remembrement) . Between 1944 and 2006, roughly 18 million hectares of agricultural land - more than half of the French Usable Agricultural Area -  have been reallocated in France. This is, I believe, the major land reallocation event in France since the French Revolution. The basic principles of land reallocation have been edicted by the Vichy government in March 1941. The main aim was to decrease morcelling by regrouping land around each farm in order to decrease the transportation time between plots of land and to have larger and more regular plots of land more suitable for the adoption of modern technologies as the tractor and the plough. Concretely, the process of land reallocation takes place at the commune level, the smallest administrative unit in France, roughly of the size of a US census tract. Each plot of agricultural land is attributed to a class reflecting is quality. The project of land reallocation is proposed by a professional surveyor and has to satisfy an equivalence constraint: the area of each class of land that each farmer possesses has to be the same in both the initial and the final allocation. After reallocation, each farmer thus possesses the same amount of land of the same quality as before, but regrouped in larger plots around his house.

The first key question that this project seeks to answer is whether land reallocation has caused a surge in agricultural productivity. At first sight, the evidence seems extremely favorable. Over the same period as that of land reallocation, French agriculture has undergone a deep structural transformation. Between 1950 and 1997, the number of tractors has increased ten-fold, the average farm size has almost tripled and yields have skyrocketed (multiplied by 6 for maize, by 4 for wheat). At the same time, the share of the active population working in the farming sector decreased from 27% to 4% and the number of farmers decreased from 2.3 million to .7. This phenomenon has been coined "The End of the Paesants" by the French sociologist Henri Mendras and "The Quiet Revolution", by the leader of farmers' unions Michel Debatisse.

Without further investigation, though, it would be misleading to attribute the bulk of the structural transformation of French agriculture to land reallocation. Indeed, many other changes might explain part of the exceptional structural transformation. First, other agricultural policies where put in place at the same time as land reallocation was encouraged. The very important Laws of Agricultural Orientation of 1960 and 1962 due to the General de Gaulle and his Ministry of Agriculture Edgar Pisani have not only facilitated land reallocation, they have created a host of other policies aiming at increasing farm size and spurring investment in agriculture. A first set of policies altered the land market, favoring renters over owners. Starting in 1945, land rents were supervised with limited price increases, investments could be decided independently by the tenant which had to be compensated in case the investment was not fully amortized at the end of the lease agreement, and the tenant had the right to preempt the land he rented in case the owner wanted to sell. In 1970, longer lease terms of 18 and 25 years were introduced. A public structure (the SAFER) could preempt any land transaction and sell its holdins to a candidate of its choice. A second set of policies favored the installation of younger farmers on farms of larger sizes. A minimum installation size (MIS) was defined and the SAFER had to sell their holding favourably to farms larger than the MIS. Starting in 1962, a set of subsidies for early retirement was put into place, with the aim of freeing land occupied by small farmers for young farmers. Subsidized loans were also directed towards farmers with the larger farm sizes. Starting in 1973, a subsidy for the installation of young farmers is created. In 1962, subsidized prices were introduced as part of the Common Agricultural Policy. Over this period, a strong movement of adaptation of (mainly U.S.) agricultural innovations was set into motion with the creation of INRA in 1946 and of the CNEEMA in 1955. These innovations were then transferred to farmers by a very dense network of farmers' groups, the CETA.  (And yes, the French love acronyms.)

In order to separate the effect of land reallocation from that of other concomitant policies, I plan to use the slow progression of land reallocation over time and space. By comparing the evolution of agricultural productivity of similar communes over time, some undergoing reparcelling and some not, or at a later date, I can separate the effect of land reallocation from that of other concomitant policies, since these other policies should affect these similar communes similarly.

An interesting feature of reparcelling is that it has affected land allocation in two ways. In the short run, it has reallocated land keeping total hodlings and quality constant. The only effect has been to regroup land into larger plots closer to the farm headquarters. The first effect of reparcelling is thus to correct for misallocation of land across space. The second effect has been (I suspect) to increase farm size by facilitating land transactions between old and young farmers. The first type of reallocation effect has never been documented to my knowledge. It would be interesting to disentangle both, but in a first step, I only plan to study the combined effect of both these types of reallocation.

Next steps

The first important step is to build a database of all the land reallocation operations in France since 1945 at the commune level, with information at least on the date of the operation. This has been kindly provided by Nadine Polombo, who has worked extensively on this topic with her colleague Marc-André Philippe. They have compiled and updated a database maintained by the French Ministry of Agriculture.

The next step for me is now to study in detail the progression of land reallocation over the years and over space and to relate it to several characteristics of farms. One easy thing to do is to look at the differences in farm structure in 2000 between communes that have been reparcelled and commune  that have not. One problem is that these communes may differ for reasons other than reparcelling. One important fact about reparcelling is that it is mainly confined to the northern part of France. Several possible explanations have been given for this fact. For example, land reallocation operations took place preferentially in open flat land of homogeneous quality. It also seems that regions with a long tradition of land rental witnessed more reparcelling and started it earlier. As a result, communes that have reparcelled were initially different: flat land favorable to crops and high yield varieties, maybe already larger farms. Even in the absence of reparcelling, these communes would have evolved differently. We say that these differences confound the effect of reparcelling. 

In order to minimize the impact of the confounding differences, I plan to use strategies:
1/ Compare communes located closely enough to each other, in areas with similar productive characteristics,
2/ Compare the evolution over time between communes that have reparcelled and communes that have not. This approach is called "difference in differences," since we compare how differences between communes change over time. Difference in difference works when the effect of confounding factors remains fixed over time. This might not be an attractive assumption since it might very well be the case that structural change would have been quicker and steeper in reparcelling communes. I will have to explore other strategies for modeling the evolution of modernization in the absence of reparcelling. There are several econometric techniques around which might be suitable. One key condition for applying this method is to access data on older farm censuses. Accessing the first farm census of 1955 would be ideal, since the bulk of land reallocation took place after that date and we thus have an initial benchmark to which to compare the subsequent evolution.
3/ Compare communes that have been reparcelled to communes that have not for reasons uncorrelated with the modernization of agriculture. For example, around 10% of all reparcelling operations have taken place along major infrastructure projects as roads or railroads. It is possible to estimate the effect of reparceloing by comparing communes located close to infrastructure projects to communes located farther away.

TBC.

Echoes from the European Summer Syposium in Labor Economics

I have not posted much recently. I am back on the tracks now. Here is a post I could have published a long time ago relating the papers that have been presented at a symposium I attended this fall.

I have spent three days at the ESSLE. This has been a really nice event extremely well organized in a delicious place. I've met really nice people, received encouragements and comments on my own research and have been exposed to some nice work. Let me here give a brief overview of some of the papers and posters that I have been exposed to. As I was presenting my own work in a poster session, I was not able to attend some of the presentations. Also, some of the work presented was too far from my own area of expertise for me to be able to comment on it.

Christina Gathmann showed that mass layoffs affect negatively local areas not only through the already documented negative long term effects on laid off workers, but also decrease total local employment in other firms. Javier Ortega brought evidence that immigration seems to have detrimental effects on the wages of blue collar workers in France. This would suggest that all the protests against immigration that we hear on the extreme right might have some empirical support. The effect seems to be especially major for construction workers. Christian Fons-Rosen presented evidence that former employees of big firms explore more risky and new ideas when they start their own firms, and produce higher quality research but with more variance. It seems to suggest that big firms are not an engine for radical ideas. Thomas Le Barbanchon showed that hiring subsidies (exemption of social taxes) have boosted employment in French firms during the recession, especially in slack labor markets. This is important because it shows that supply side reforms might have an effect even when demand is depressed. Ankita Patnaik showed that the move to a compulsory parental leave of 5 weeks for daddies in Quebec (required minimum amount of daddy's leave duration for mums to be able to take their own leave) generated not only an increase in the duration of daddy's leave by 3 weeks from an initial level of 2 weeks but also seems to have generated strong changes in intra household behavior that lasts after the parental leave period is over: dads spend less time at work, take more time for chores and earn less money whereas mums earn more money, do less chores and spend more time with their families. In my opinion,the results on earnings were very large, suggesting that there might be selection bias due to couples delaying or accelerating the decision to have a child because of the reform. Andrea Bassanini showed that in France the probability of layoffs seems to increase with the distance of a plant to its headquarters. This might be because of local social pressure not to hurt local employment or as a service to the local authorities. Kristina Huttunen showed evidence that offshoring might have negative effects on employment across industries but seem to have a positive effect within industries: firms that offshore part of their production seem to expand. The reverse is true for import competition. Nishith Prakash shows that you can obtain a substantial increase of enrollment in high school by girls in India by buying them a bike to ride to school. 

The second day, Stefania Albanesi documented that the increase in women labor force participation is slowing down in the US and in other OECD countries while at the same time the decrease in the gender wage gap slows down. She related that to the increase in top wages: women married to men whose wages have rapidly increased in the last decades do not need to work and thus take more time off the job market, yielding to lower salaries. My attention somewhat decreased thereafter, not doubt because the time of my own presentation was getting closer but also because I am less familiar with the topics covered. I apologize to Pietro Garibaldi and Gerard Pfann for not reporting on their work. Konstantinos Tatsiramos showed that the effects of school and community of people lifetime earnings seemed to stem mainly from the ignorance of the fact that family self select to schools and neighborhoods. Once taking this correlation into account, he finds that school and community do not seem to have strong effects on lifetime earnings. Ulf Zolitz presented in the poster session a very nice paper using the random assignement of students to classes to show that low achieving students benefit from having better classmates, but not the best classmates. The negative effect of the best students on the weak students is an interesting finding. Actually, Ulf has also a paper on the negative learning effects of cannabis usage. He cleverly exploits a local law forbidding French citizens to consume pot in the Netherlands. 

Finally, the third day, Erich Battistin presented a paper revisiting the famous Maimonides' rule approach for estimating the effect of class size on students' achievement. I am not going to describe this classical approach here. Erich shows that this classical result can be found in Italy, but only in the south. Because the south is also known for forging test scores, Erich and his coauthors suspect a link between the two phenomena. They actually show that a decrease in class size seems to improves test scores only by an increase in test misreporting. I do not remember the proposed mechanism, but the result is counterintuitive at first sight (smaller class is easier to grade and thus misreporting is less of an issue, though active cheating is easier). David Jaeger showed evidence from an experiment that halving class time only decreased test scores in a university introductory economics course by a few points, suggesting that class time could be reduced without strong detrimental effects on learning. Stefano Verzillo showed evidence that Italian academics seem to react to the competitive pressure exerted by peers at the time of promotion: the more competition they face, the more they work if they are already good. The reverse is true for scientists with a lower publication record. I apologize to Rainer Winkelmann and Winfried Koeninger for not relating the content of their talks.


Wednesday, October 15, 2014

Joy, pride and emotion

Yesterday, my boss has been awarded the Nobel Prize in economics. The feelings it generates are hard to describe, but over the whole day yesterday I went through a succession of joy, pride and emotion.

Joy when I learned about the award. I was attending Alexandra Roulet's seminar, and right in the middle of the seminar, I heard PhD students shouting and laughing, hi-fiving each other. I turned, ready to ask them to keep a respectful attitude during the talk, but they interrupted me saying "you realy wanna know about this. He won! He won!" "Who won what?" I answered. Despite having formulated the prediction that Jean would win with .15 probability just in the morning, I was so focused on the seminar that I had completely forgotten about the timing of the announcement. "Jean! He won the Nobel prize" they shouted in reply. I was flabbergasted, then overflowed with an intense joy. I apologized to Alexandra, interrupted the seminar and we had a round of applause. Then, we resumed the seminar, but a smile was on everyone's face, and it won't leave us for the rest of the day. This is, I think, what Jean would have wanted. When he was asked about what the prize was going to change in his life, he answered "Nothing, I hope, I like my life as it is, I love research and interacting with colleagues. I wake up every morning happy to go to work. I want this to go on."

When we got out of the room, we could feel that something was different. Everyone was smiling and congratulating each other, despite the fact that we had won nothing for ourselves. Then the word got out that Jean was going to have a press conference. And that's when things started to get crazy. All the media were there, TV stations with their cars equipped with immense antennas, radio, papers. They were interviewing researchers, students, everyone. I might have mumbled stupid words to some mics. The students wore Tshirts with "I love Jean", and they sang "He won the prize, He won the prize". We were all so proud. Later in the evening, when I picked up my kid late at daycare, I apologized, explaining that my boss had just won the Nobel. The nannies looked at me, they smiled and cheered, because they were proud that someone in Toulouse had won this distinction. It is actually the second Nobel prize in Toulouse, after Paul Sabatier more than a hundred years ago.

When Jean entered the press conference room, he smiled, but you could see he was moved. The first thing he did was to hug Colette Laffont, the widow of Jean-Jacques Laffont, the longtime mentor, coauthor and friend of Jean and the founding father of TSE. He was moved to tears. Actually, yesterday, when he was honored by the university for his achievement, he ended his speech by saying that he had a thought for all his colleagues that contributed to the research that the prize celebrates, and "especially for Jean-Jacques Laffont, who, had he not died much too young, would be here, by my side, and would share this prize with me." He almost could not finished his sentence, and he started to cry. It was a deeply moving moment. I was moved to tears, and not the only one in the room. You see, when you work at TSE, even if you have never met him, you can feel the long shadow that Jean-Jacques Laffont casts on this place, almost everyone can share a positive story about Jean-Jacques, and we know what we owe him, that without him, this place would never have existed, this place that, when you get up to go to work every morning, you are happy, and you have a smile on your face, all the more so since last monday. Every morning, I cycle past the Jean-Jacques Laffont roundabout on my way to work, and I was proud before, and I am moved now. This prize crowns a beautiful human adventure, and if you watch closely Jean lecture in Stockholm, I'm sure you'll be able to see the long shadow of Jean-Jacques standing just beside him, smiling and celebrating, as he did the very day when Jean decided to stay definitely in Toulouse with him.

Sunday, September 28, 2014

The (Crazy?) Dream of George Udny Yule: Is Non Experimental Causal Inference Feasible?



In 1899, George Udny Yule published a fundamental paper for economics and statistics. In this paper, he proposed to use the method of ordinary least squares to estimate the causal effect of policy variables on outcomes. Actually, the theory was outlined in a 1897 paper and the 1899 paper is the application of the theory of non-experimental causal inference to the estimation of the effect of anti-poverty policies on poverty. By so doing, Yule was setting up a method and a problem that would haunt applied economists for decades and that one hundred years later, is still unsolved.  Some of my own research is trying to revisit this problem. I like Yule's problem because it is an engineering problem and some of the most beautiful engineering results in economics stem from trying to solve this problem, or checking whether the solutions we have do work or not. I also like it because Yule's writing is crystal clear and one would be hard-pressed to try to come up with a cleanest formulation of both the issue and the solution. This is the first post of a series examining the history of non experimental causal inference that will end up with descriptions of some of my current work.

Before detailing the 1899 paper, I would like to quote the introduction to the 1897 paper that is extremely clear on what Yule is doing:



For Yule, the main problem of economists and social scientists is the inability to make experiments. This state of fact has long plagued economics and has lead to the emergence of econometrics. Starting in the 70s, and sometimes even before, experimental methods have started to be used in economics and are now developing at a very large speed.

If you cannot perform experiments, you have to rely on the data of daily experience, a.k.a. observational data. The most pressing problem with observational data is that of confounding factors: factors that simultaneoulsy affect the variable of interest and the outcome variable. Let's be more concrete with Yule's 1899 paper. In this paper, Yule examines whether the strictness of the application of antipoverty laws has an impact on poverty rates. In england at the time were two types of relief offered to the poor: In-relief and Out-relief (See Stephen Stigler's wonderful book for more detail). In-relief or "indoors relief" was given to able bodied individuals taken into workhouses where they would perform various tasks in returns for their subsistence. Out-relief or "out of doors relief" was assistance given in their own homes to persons judged unable to work, e.g. the old or the infirm. A larger proportion of Out-relief was considered to signal a lenient administration.It was clamied at Yule's time that the strictness of the administration was not linked with the poverty rate. In previous work, Yule had shown that this was false and that there was a positive correlation between poverty and the proportion of Out-relief. This seemed to favor a stricter application of the antipoverty laws.

But as Yule was well aware of, correlation is not causation. In his 1899 paper, Yule tackles the difficult task of trying to infer the causal effect of the change in the proportion of Out-relief on the change in poverty. Yule first lists 5 distinct groups of causes that might affect the changes in the rate of poverty:



He then goes on to explain his interest in the first group in a way that no modern economist would deny:

Finally, Yule describes extremely accurately the problem of confounding factors:


An increase in the proportion of the aged, in Yule's example, would simultaneously increase the proportion of Out-relief and the poverty rate. At the same time, the correlation between Out-relief and poverty would be positive but not causal: this is not because there is more Out-relief that there is more poverty, but because there are more elderly. Distinguishing between mere correlation and true causality is a very important task in this case, since we would like to know whether a policy and the way it is implemented can have an effect on poverty, and not whether being older increases poverty. Yule claims that he has an adequate method to solve the problem of confounding factors.

What is this method? Suppose that you could have data on all these variables, says Yule. If you were to use this data to estimate the parameter B in the following simple model, you would have a problem:

 
So what can we do?


Yule argues that by estimating the parameters of this simple multiple linear regression, he can measure the effect of the policy net of all the other influences, ceteris paribus. The regression and econometric adjustment have taken the place of the experiment. By using data and econometrics to control for the influence of the confounding factors, Yule claims that we can conduct causal inference almost as good as in an experiment. Hence, we call this type of approach non-experimental causal inference. The key question obviously is whether the chance of error is now much smaller than before, as Yule argues, or if some missing external influence still messes with the relationship of interest. This is what we will examine in the next posts. The methodological impact of Yule's work has been far-reaching. Today, most social scientists still use the linear model to estimate causal effects. Yule was well aware that the true relationships were not linear, but he argued that he could capture an average effect.

In practice, Yule estimates the parameters of equation (2) above by minimizing the sum of the squared residuals of this equation. He finds the following result:


An increase in Out-relief of 10 percent increases poverty by roughly 3 percent. Thus the positive raw correlation between Out-relief and poverty did not seem to mask a negative relationship. The size of the effect is much smaller though after accounting for the porportion of old and the population. Indeed, the raw correlation coefficient was .38, almost a third more. Thus, multiple regression enables one to pin down more efficently and precisely causal effects.

Yule's paper is extremely rich and any student could take inspiration from it. For example, Yule uses his estimates to decompose the total variation in poverty rate between factors due the policy and other factors:


We can wee that even if unkwown factors were responsible for the majority of the poverty decrease in rural and mixed areas, the increase in the severity of the relief policy (and the resulting decrease in Out-relief) have been a major factor in decreasing the urban poverty rate, at least between 1871 and 1881.

Yule's beautiful analysis withstand the test of time. The main question for its validity is whether the important factors that have been left out and that account for a majority of the variation in poverty are also correlated with Out-relief. If this is the case, they are still biasing Yule's estimates. This is the key question that nonexperimental causal inference has to answer. That is, we still do not know whether the method that Yule has devised is really competent to extract causal relationships from the data of daily experience.

I've also just become aware that Yule can be credited as being the inventor the the Difference In Difference Matching method that I study in my own work. More on this in subsequent posts.

Monday, September 15, 2014

History of econometrics: special conference session at the EEA-ESEM meeting

One of my secret manias (and one that I am less ashamed to admit) is an interest for the history of econometrics. With such an inclination, the two successive sessions of the EEA-ESEM meeting on the history of econometric thought were obviously an absolute delight to me. Here, I am going to try to convey some of the excitement that I got out of this sessions by giving a quick summary of the papers presented. This post will also appear in the next issue of the TSE Mag.

In the first talk of the first session, John Aldrich detailed how the father of modern econometrics  Trygve Haavelmo, contributed to the understanding and formalization of the concept of causality. John especially emphasized the modernity of Haavelmo's views on this topic and how they have resurfaced in more recent literature. Marcel Boumans described the interaction between Milton Friedman and the members of the Cowles Commission, the founders of modern econometrics. Both interacted in the late forties in Chicago. Marcel gave a fascinating account of how much Friedman was involved into methodological debates at the time, that eventually yielded to the writing of his essays in positive economics. Friedman was at the time extremely critical of the strong theorisation of econometrics promoted but the then Commission president Tjalling Koopmans (Marcel quoted from an unpublished assessment by Friedman of the works of the Cowles commission). At some point, Friedman defied Koopmans and one of his boys, Lawrence Klein, to check whether the complex macro simultaneous equations model estimated on pre-war data could predict macro conditions in 1948. This was a dismal failure and yielded Klein to reassess his model. Marcel put this debate in perspective by recalling how it related to the views of early economists Alfred Marshall on one side and Léon Walras on the other. Till Dueppe presented a thorough account of a trip taken by Tjalling Koopmans to the Soviet Union in 1976. Koopmans was really eager to discover if the linear programming methods developed by Leonid Kantorovich were applied in practice by the planning bureau of the Soviet Union. What he found was a very dispirited Kantorovitch, saying that they might have read about it, at least it was somewhere in published form. Koopmans was also somewhat disappointed by the quality of economics research that he found there. He was on the other hand extremely impressed to meet with some of the most outstanding mathematicians of the world.

The next session started with a minutely accurate detail of the first meeting of the econometrics society in 1931 in Lausanne by Olav Bjerkholt. What striked me the most was the impressive imprint that Ragnar Frish left on this meeting and on the early years of the econometric society. While François Divisia, the Vice President officially in charge of organizing the meeting was preoccupied by such urgent matters as choosing the suitable French translation of "econometrician," Frish used his spare time while recovering from a skiing accident to write a sketch of a programme and one of the three papers he presented at the conference. Frish also insisted that the conference opened with a presentation of some of the works of six of the founding fathers of economics (Marshall was not one of them). This echoes evidence given by Marcel Boumans that early Econometrica issues published handwritten notes by Walras, along with his correspondence with other economists. Duo Qin advocated the return of the use of the terms autonomy and confluence in modern econometrics textbooks. These terms have been coined by Frish to separate what we now call structural and reduced form relationships. These late notions were in fact derived from the earlier notions by Tjallling Koopmans. The great advantage of the term "autonomy" is that it puts emphasis on the fact that we are looking for invariant relationships that remain true when the other relations in the economy change. The Lucas critique is in a sense a mere application of the notion of autonomy, which Lucas acknowledged explicitly in his paper (see the reference to Marschak in footnote 3). Cléo Chassonery-Zaïgouche presented the evolution over the years of the empirical analysis of discrimination. She especially showed that the traditional econometric techniques developed in the 70s in the Cowles tradition are progressively replaced by experiments. This trend is not apparent in the number of papers published in top journals though, but is clear in the influence of the published papers: experiments gain much more citations. Finally Jan Höffler presented an exciting collaborative wiki project on replication in economics. With his colleagues, he has set up a list of the published papers in top journals with a link to the data sets and code. With his students, they are now trying to replicate the authors' findings. Being a collaborative project, anyone can report the results of his own replication exercise on the web page. An exciting exercise for students in econometrics.


Sunday, August 31, 2014

Let's open the scientific kitchen!

I am an academic economist and I am starting a blog. What I would like to do is to take the prospective readers (if any) throughout the journey of a young academic economist trying to advance economic science along with his own career.

For me, this blog would serve as a sort of lab notebook, where I register my ideas, thoughts, trials and errors and eventual results. This would be very helpful for me to keep track of my thought process, how I came to my results. It will also serve to polish my understanding and explaining of what I'm doing along the way, something that I think will prove critical when writing the final paper. I also would like this blog to be a sort of disciplinary device incentivizing me not to procrastinate too much on a project, by making explicit how much time has elapsed since I said I would do something. On the downside, one could say that blogging is the ultimate procrastination device. I hope not, and I want to see whether it works. Finally, I will indulge occasionally in one of my sinful pleasures: methology and history of science, especially of economics.

One of my hopes is that this blog gives a picture of the inner workings of my work, and thus contributes to give the audience a better understanding of how scientists in general, and economists in particular, work. Terence Tao's blog about his mathematical research is a beautiful example of what one can achieve in this respect. My hope is that in this way, we can overcome the occasional distrust that citizens have towards scientific work by opening up the machinery of what we are doing. This is a similar undertaking as the open kitchen movement in restaurants. Clients like it because it signals that the chef has nothing to hide, he does everything in the open, he has nothing to be ashamed of. Blogging opens the box of one's own methods and choices and hopefully participates to convince nonscientists that we have nothing to hide, and that everything is in the open for them to see. Maybe in the future, with more scientific blogging, we can decrease the likelihood of controversies such as the Climatic Research Unit email controversy or the one about the reproducibility of psychological research.

In order to start this blog, I have to overcome my own "academic paranoia", the fear that my unfinished ideas get stolen. Time and again, I've had this feeling that I am not particularly proud of, the reluctance to expose budding ideas publicly, for the fear that someone might get inspired by them and write a paper in the meantime. There is also the related fear of triggering an attrition war. If someone hears about me working on some topic, he might hurry to finish a related work. Think of Andrew Wiles locking himself up in his attic to crack Fermat's last theorem, after accumulating a bundle of papers to send each year for publication, in order to distract possible competitors and convince them that he was not working on proving Fermat's last theorem but still following his old research path, as Simon Singh reports. Related is the fear of a precedence war to decide who has come with an idea first. Michel Moreaux told me that Econometrica received 2 papers proving general equilibrium theory within 6 months in 1960 1952. There is actually a recent book on this topic. A few weeks ago a colleague told me that he received an email of a researcher that has conducted a very similar research, and that he did not know how to react.
 
My feeling is that being more open about which research we are pursuing since the start might help to make it clearer who contributed to what on a given topic. One very nice way to establish priority is to have blog entries showing the way your research unfolded. Tim Gowers made some excellent points on this topic when he launched the collaborative Polymath project. My experience is that sharing ideas early on generally makes me clarify them and has a major effect on the direction I eventually take. It might also help to identify potential collaborations very early along the way, etc.

Let's tame the fear then and let me take you for a journey in my scientific kitchen.